Saturday, August 4, 2012

Chick-fil-A

 


Chick-fil-A closes its doors every Sunday for religious reasons. So when its founder, Dan Cathy, finally spoke publicly about marriage, did you expect anything but what he said? Is the outrage directed at him for talking about his beliefs, or is it aimed at the religion he professes faith in?


I am not always the most informed consumer, but I was not surprised by Cathy's comments. A successful business owner with strong religious convictions is likely to use some of his company's profits to support causes he cares about. This is healthy behavior in a democratic political system. The Cathy family has been politically active for years; forgoing profits on Sundays was a huge indicator of the intensity of their convictions.


The Cathy family could have hidden behind a veil of neutrality, as some wealthy Americans are doing in this year's presidential campaign. They did not, and I applaud that, even though I disagree with them on this issue.


Social media make informed shopping easier, as this family is learning. I support disclosure and wish there were more of it in the political sphere.

Tuesday, July 24, 2012

Political Moderates

I assume the cultural divisions in our country are not new. They have been with us at least going back to the 60s. Why are moderates less effective today than in the past?


One obvious, and probably the most important, variable is the economy. If the economy doesn't change much, when this Nov's election occurs, the unemployment rate will be as high as it's been ON election day since at least WWII. A negative outlook on the economy surely exacerbates other divisions, especially how people view the role of government. So when the economy is slumping, there is less incentive for politicians to compromise. At a time when more compromise is needed there is less of an incentive for it. Unfortunately, moderates are squeezed out during periods when the system is more polarized, as it is now.


Moderates have always existed in both parties and, in the not too distant past, have tended to lead. Politicians always want to get reelected. That’s a given. And genuine cultural divisions have existed for two generations. Besides the economy, what else has changed?


The amount of money now flowing into the system coupled with the current tendency for ideologically pure candidates to attract that money is the death knell for moderates in Congress. In addition, there has been increased use of the filibuster. The filibuster ought to encourage compromise, but it doesn’t. As it’s currently used, it all but guarantees gridlock, further incentivizing political posturing.


When the economy improves, will today’s ideologues become tomorrow’s moderates? Will moderates be able to return to Washington?

http://data.bls.gov/timeseries/LNS14000000

Friday, July 20, 2012

Health Care and Markets



The Unites States is a country of great wealth (1). This wealth is spread unevenly, and, for the most part, people accept that. That’s how capitalism works.  Differences in wealth are ok, capitalists point out, as long as everyone’s standard of living is high. Yet, more than 40 million Americans are without health insurance.  While some choose to go without coverage, deciding that it is in their best interest to remain uninsured, many want coverage but cannot get it. A number of factors explain why people may not have health insurance, including unemployment or working for an employer that does not offer medical benefits.  


On a moral level, for a country with such tremendous wealth to leave so many people without health insurance is unconscionable. Challenging such a forceful judgement, capitalists argue that expecting a market, any market, to NOT leave people out is irrational. Naturally, they continue, without intervention, some people are and always will be left out of most markets, usually due to a lack of money.  A core issue in the health care debate, then, revolves around how best to address those left out of the health insurance market. To think deeper about markets, it helps to review what they are and how they function.

In economics textbooks, a market is described as an environment where buyers and sellers freely interact with each other for the purpose of conducting mutually beneficial exchanges. Some sellers may attract lots of consumer attention, while others are barely noticed. Why? Either the products a business is selling are judged undesirable by consumers or their prices are too high. Markets reward business owners who provide goods and services that are desired by the public. Businesses that do this and can do it with low prices are rewarded even more. If multiple business owners are competing for the same customers, even better. Prices decline to attract customers and consumers benefit. 

       While the real word is complicated, this basic textbook description of a market should sound familiar. On a daily basis in the United States, we are surrounded by businesses competing for our dollars. The Internet, with websites such as E-Bay and Craigslist, provide consumers with ample opportunities to interact in virtual markets, proving that one person's junk is another person's treasure. Can the power of the market be harnessed to provide a solution to our health care system? Or, do we have millions of uninsured in our country precisely because we have relied too heavily on markets? And what role, if any, does the federal government play in addressing these issues? (more posts on this topic to come!)                           
1. US ranks 11th GDP per capita (https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-world-factbook/rankorder/2004rank.html)
I haven't reached 50 posts on Absolute Write, but any basic feedback on my writing, or the topic, is appreciated greatly. Thanks! I will be sure to stop by your blog as well. 
  

Thursday, July 19, 2012

Reading Hayek's "A Pretense of Knowledge" (1974)

http://mises.org/daily/3229

1. "The particular occasion of this lecture, combined with the chief practical problem which economists have to face today, have made the choice of its topic almost inevitable. On the one hand the still recent establishment of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Science marks a significant step in the process by which, in the opinion of the general public, economics has been conceded some of the dignity and prestige of the physical sciences. On the other hand, the economists are at this moment called upon to say how to extricate the free world from the serious threat of accelerating inflation which, it must be admitted, has been brought about by policies which the majority of economists recommended and even urged governments to pursue. We have indeed at the moment little cause for pride: as a profession we have made a mess of things."

Does economics deserve to be treated like the phsycial sciences?
Written in 1974, during a time of increasing inflation.
Hayek blames the profession for supporting policies that have led to this outcome.

2. "It seems to me that this failure of the economists to guide policy more successfully is closely connected with their propensity to imitate as closely as possible the procedures of the brilliantly successful physical sciences — an attempt which in our field may lead to outright error. It is an approach which has come to be described as the "scientistic" attitude — an attitude which, as I defined it some thirty years ago, "is decidedly unscientific in the true sense of the word, since it involves a mechanical and uncritical application of habits of thought to fields different from those in which they have been formed."[1] I want today to begin by explaining how some of the gravest errors of recent economic policy are a direct consequence of this scientistic error."

Critical of economists imitating procedures of the physical scientists.
Calls this scientific atttitude/mentality "decidely unscientific."

3. "The theory which has been guiding monetary and financial policy during the last thirty years, and which I contend is largely the product of such a mistaken conception of the proper scientific procedure, consists in the assertion that there exists a simple positive correlation between total employment and the size of the aggregate demand for goods and services; it leads to the belief that we can permanently assure full employment by maintaining total money expenditure at an appropriate level. Among the various theories advanced to account for extensive unemployment, this is probably the only one in support of which strong quantitative evidence can be adduced. I nevertheless regard it as fundamentally false (why?), and to act upon it, as we now experience, as very harmful."

-Correlation between total employment (all who want to work are working. low unemployment. + the size of the aggregate demand for good and service. How is AD measured? quantified?) These two are coorealted, says Hayek, but, seems like he will argue, not a causal relationship)
-Isn't this a reference to the view of Keynesians that spending can boost the economy?
-Why is unemployment high? What was unemployment in the US in 1974?
-U today is currently in the 8% range.
-Big Idea-- Just because you can measure a cause does not mean it is the only possible factor influencing the effect.

4. This brings me to the crucial issue. Unlike the position that exists in the physical sciences, in economics and other disciplines that deal with essentially complex phenomena, the aspects of the events to be accounted for about which we can get quantitative data are necessarily limited and may not include the important ones. While in the physical sciences it is generally assumed, probably with good reason (why with good reason?), that any important factor which determines the observed events will itself be directly observable and measurable (is this valid?), in the study of such complex phenomena as the market, which depend on the actions of many individuals, all the circumstances which will determine the outcome of a process, for reasons which I shall explain later, will hardly ever be fully known or measurable. And while in the physical sciences the investigator will be able to measure what, on the basis of a prima facie (first look, first blush) theory, he thinks important, in the social sciences often that is treated as important which happens to be accessible to measurement. This is sometimes carried to the point where it is demanded that our theories must be formulated in such terms that they refer only to measurable magnitudes. (why would something important to an effect not be measurable? Seems like a reflection of complexity)

5. It can hardly be denied that such a demand quite arbitrarily limits the facts which are to be admitted as possible causes of the events which occur in the real world. This view, which is often quite naively accepted as required by scientific procedure (is not?), has some rather paradoxical consequences. We know, of course, with regard to the market and similar social structures, a great many facts which we cannot measure and on which indeed we have only some very imprecise and general information (like what?). And because the effects of these facts in any particular instance cannot be confirmed by quantitative evidence (what is qualititative evidence?), they are simply disregarded by those sworn to admit only what they regard as scientific evidence (what is evidence? scientific evidence? unscientific evidence?): they thereupon happily proceed on the fiction that the factors which they can measure are the only ones that are relevant.

 so for example, making a connect to the Colo. shooting, just knowing the # of guns in the US vs another country might not alone explain what happened. More complicated than that.

6. The correlation between aggregate demand and total employment, for instance, may only be approximate, but as it is the only one on which we have quantitative data, it is accepted as the only causal connection that counts. On this standard there may thus well exist better "scientific" evidence for a false theory, which will be accepted because it is more "scientific," than for a valid explanation, which is rejected because there is no sufficient quantitative evidence for it.

7. Let me illustrate this by a brief sketch of what I regard as the chief actual cause of extensive unemployment — an account which will also explain why such unemployment cannot be lastingly cured by the inflationary policies recommended by the now fashionable theory (can unemployment be solved? eliminated?). This correct explanation appears to me to be the existence of discrepancies between the distribution of demand among the different goods and services and the allocation of labor and other resources among the production of those outputs. We possess a fairly good "qualitative" knowledge of the forces by which a correspondence between demand and supply in the different sectors of the economic system is brought about, of the conditions under which it will be achieved, and of the factors likely to prevent such an adjustment. The separate steps in the account of this process rely on facts of everyday experience, and few who take the trouble to follow the argument will question the validity of the factual assumptions, or the logical correctness of the conclusions drawn from them. We have indeed good reason to believe that unemployment indicates that the structure of relative prices and wages has been distorted (usually by monopolistic or governmental price fixing), and that to restore equality between the demand and the supply of labor in all sectors changes of relative prices and some transfers of labor will be necessary.

What is unemployment? What does it mean? What is it a sign of?

8. But when we are asked for quantitative evidence for the particular structure of prices and wages that would be required in order to assure a smooth continuous sale of the products and services offered, we must admit that we have no such information. We know, in other words, the general conditions in which what we call, somewhat misleadingly, an equilibrium will establish itself; but we never know what the particular prices or wages are which would exist if the market were to bring about such an equilibrium. We can merely say what the conditions are in which we can expect the market to establish prices and wages at which demand will equal supply. But we can never produce statistical information which would show how much the prevailing prices and wages deviate from those which would secure a continuous sale of the current supply of labor. Though this account of the causes of unemployment is an empirical theory — in the sense that it might be proved false, e.g., if, with a constant money supply, a general increase of wages did not lead to unemployment — it is certainly not the kind of theory which we could use to obtain specific numerical predictions concerning the rates of wages, or the distribution of labor, to be expected.

9. Why should we, however, in economics, have to plead ignorance of the sort of facts on which, in the case of a physical theory, a scientist would certainly be expected to give precise information? It is probably not surprising that those impressed by the example of the physical sciences should find this position very unsatisfactory and should insist on the standards of proof which they find there. The reason for this state of affairs is the fact, to which I have already briefly referred, that the social sciences, like much of biology but unlike most fields of the physical sciences, have to deal with structures of essential complexity, i.e., with structures whose characteristic properties can be exhibited only by models made up of relatively large numbers of variables. Competition, for instance, is a process which will produce certain results only if it proceeds among a fairly large number of acting persons.

10. In some fields, particularly where problems of a similar kind arise in the physical sciences, the difficulties can be overcome by using, instead of specific information about the individual elements, data about the relative frequency, or the probability, of the occurrence of the various distinctive properties of the elements. But this is true only where we have to deal with what has been called by Dr. Warren Weaver (formerly of the Rockefeller Foundation), with a distinction which ought to be much more widely understood, "phenomena of unorganized complexity," in contrast to those "phenomena of organized complexity" with which we have to deal in the social sciences.[2]

11. Organized complexity here means that the character of the structures showing it depends not only on the properties of the individual elements of which they are composed, and the relative frequency with which they occur, but also on the manner in which the individual elements are connected with each other. In the explanation of the working of such structures we can for this reason not replace the information about the individual elements by statistical information, but require full information about each element if from our theory we are to derive specific predictions about individual events. Without such specific information about the individual elements we shall be confined to what on another occasion I have called mere pattern predictions — predictions of some of the general attributes of the structures that will form themselves, but not containing specific statements about the individual elements of which the structures will be made up.[3]

Monday, July 16, 2012

The Habit of Writing + My Writing Goals


Establishing habits are difficult. I know this. And as quickly as a habit is established, others may fade, and the new habit can easily be lost if you are not careful. Nevertheless, I am excited to be writing each day- 750 words, give or take a few, to be precise.


Each morning I get up and write for about 20 to 40 minutes. This writing is off the top of my head, stream of conscious style. I have been doing this each day since the third week of June, with the exception of a week-long family vacation. I like that I am doing this, but I want to do more than just write whatever I am thinking for 30 minutes each morning. I want to hone my writing skills, to become a better writer.



Many lists of tips for writers say actually writing every single day is a huge step in the right direction. I am doing that. So I am ahead of people who say they want to write and never actually write. I am, indeed, writing. And the other day I printed about 7 or 8 pages of my words. It was a few thousand words, and I was impressed with the fact that I have gone from no writing, other than on the job, to 750 words each day. Keeping a habit like this going when school resumes is always a challenge, but I am up for it.


This week I am going to tinker with my habit a bit. My goal is to produce a weekly blog post that I publish on Friday that is between 400-500 words in length. It will be on a single topic and focus on the type of writing that I am trying to develop, which is in the areas of persuasive writing and current events and education.



I am thinking that after my Monday morning 750 word session I am going to decide on a topic and a tentative thesis statement. Then, during the week, I will continue focusing some of my writing on this theme, while developing my research skills. This way I can add some focus to my morning writing, while at the same time preserving much of the spontaneity of mind that this habit induces.




This week’s theme is health care.




My tentative thesis is as follows- A completely free market approach to health care is neither politically practical nor, if put into effect, desirable. (Not the most controversial thesis statement. I will refine this)

Tuesday's update of thesis- A system of health care based on profit seeking will not lead to universal coverage and quality care for all.


   


Sunday, July 15, 2012

The Importance of Knowing Your Targets

I am one of those people who, for whatever reason, always seems to be working on a fairly large number of projects at once. This seems to drive my wife nuts.  It's not like I do not finish the projects that I start, but it does take me a considerable amount of time (ongoing porch project is an example of this)




I am not sure I want, or am able, to change this aspect of my personality. But what I would like to train myself to do is to establish the habit of regularly reflecting on my targets, both short and long term, and actively measuring my progress.

My "Big 5" right now are the following, in no particular order. I've included the amount of time I want to spend on each pro this week.

-Fixing drywall in bathroom and painting this room. (4 hours)
-Digging flower bed deeper (lots of dirt to move!) and planting the flowers I purchased (also add mulch?). (2 hours)
-Continue my streak of discarding items in attic (have been doing this daily for a few weeks. keep it up!) (I do this daily, a quick task)
-Dealing with out of season clothes that need to be moved and putting current clothes in drawers in more organized way. (2 hours)
-Read 10 articles about health care so that I can develop my blog posts on that topic. (80 mins)
-Continue with 750 words a day streak! (really excited to be doing this. this comes first and has been coming first since the start of summer)


Are you a one task at a time person, or do you try to juggle multiple tasks?

What are your targets for the week?

I printed some of my daily "quick writes" of 750 words. Hopefully, I can turn some of these morning ramblings into some blog posts.